A New Kind of Labor Union

Another interesting proposal for the reform of labor unions, this time from the Right. The author’s obvious distaste for powerful workers’ unions, what he calls Big Labor, has been largely edited out of this version. Nevertheless a willingness to negotiate from either side of the dispute between labor and management needs to be listened to today.

By OREN CASS, September 1, 2017 for The New York Times

. . . much has changed since Congress passed the National Labor Relations Act in 1935—when workplaces were largely unregulated, the Great Depression had pushed Americans to the brink, and labor unrest was widespread. The NLRA’s objective was not only to empower workers but also to end what Sen. Robert Wagner, its sponsor, called “a procession of bloody and costly strikes, which in some cases swelled almost to the magnitude of national emergencies.”

Today bargaining over employment terms is mostly superfluous. The law already mandates a 40-hour week, paid overtime, a minimum wage, workplace safety standards and employer-sponsored health insurance. The government provides benefits to the elderly, disabled and unemployed. Yet unions still must find something to deliver to members. Thus the prevalence of destructive work rules, grievance procedures and seniority systems.

1936 GM auto workers’ sit-down strike in Flint, Mich.

In 1936, after hundreds of deaths in auto plants, General Motors workers in Flint, Mich., launched their famous sit-down strike. Among their demands: permission to speak in the lunchroom. . . .

The NLRA no longer accomplishes its goals. Its adversarial model pits labor against management, winning short-term “gains” for workers while reducing their long-term value. Employees seem to understand this. Since 1953 union membership has fallen from 36% of the private labor force to less than 7%, while workers’ total share of national income has increased to 66.1% from 64.5%.

As its relevance waned, Big Labor mutated into a political force. Of the $2.1 billion spent on federal elections by the 30 largest donors since 1990, unions accounted for more than $1 billion—and directed 97% to Democrats. This has locked the status quo in place: Democrats prize union money, so they shun real reform. Republicans seem content to watch the dysfunctional system wither.

What a missed opportunity. Organized labor is not inherently partisan or economically counterproductive. Under Europe’s “Ghent system,” workers voluntarily join unions independent of their jobs. Denmark and Sweden have no required workplace elections or compulsory dues, yet a majority of workers are in a union.

Scene in a Swedish car factory today

Adapting this model to the U.S. could allow new labor organizations—call them “co-ops”—to do a lot:

  • Expand social insurance. In Europe, unions administer systems of voluntary unemployment insurance. Although the vast U.S. labor market may seem dissimilar, most American social insurance is already managed by the states. Co-ops could supplement or supplant these programs.
  • Improve job training. Today’s training, run mostly by government agencies and well-meaning nonprofits, is ineffective. Putting co-ops in charge would keep training focused on workers, who measure their investment by the resulting job, not “enrollment” or “graduation.” Co-ops may be better positioned to negotiate with employers over matters like apprenticeships. . . .
  • Strengthen civil society. Co-ops could act as mediating institutions for poor and less-educated Americans, helping workers build relationships, access resources and provide mutual aid. . . .
  • Resolve problems with employers. Co-ops could help workers build collaborative relationships with management. Such arrangements exist in many countries as company-specific “works councils.” In Germany they’re present at almost 90% of companies with more than 500 employees. But works councils are prohibited in the U.S. . . .
  • Provide alternatives to government rules. The argument for employment regulation—say, the minimum wage—flows from the premise that individual workers lack the leverage to protect their interests. But co-ops bargaining collectively should be able to accept lower standards if the company offers something compelling in return. . . .
  • Support workers in the gig economy. Co-ops could extend employment-like benefits to Uber drivers, contract coders, call-center temps and other nontraditional workers. . . . Co-ops would give structure to otherwise free-floating careers.

On July 5, 1935, President Franklin D. Roosevelt signed the National Labor Relations Act to protect the rights of employees and employers, to encourage collective bargaining. The law was also known as the Wagner Act, after U.S. Sen. Robert F. Wagner (D-N.Y.), who was instrumental to passing the legislation.

How to achieve this vision? The smoothest path would involve four steps. First, amend the NLRA to allow alternative labor groups. The law covers any worker organization whose purpose is “dealing with employers.” That jurisdiction should be narrowed, while leaving current arrangements in place for union members who are satisfied.

Second, formally recognize the “labor co-operative”:  a nonprofit controlled by dues-paying members to advance employment and create value, not merely reallocate it.

Third, allow works councils. . . .  If workers began to think a council no longer represented their interests, they might have recourse to a snap “vote of no confidence.”

Fourth, let employees designate a co-op or works council as their representative for collective bargaining. Put most employment regulations on the negotiating table to create space for mutually beneficial deals.

It isn’t crazy to think labor groups should focus on delivering benefits to workers instead of campaign contributions to politicians. Or to suggest employees in the modern economy have more to gain from collaboration with their bosses than from conflict. If Democrats and Republicans want robust civil society, competitive markets, widely shared prosperity, and a stronger safety net, they have more than enough reason to give organized labor—in a new form—a fresh look.

Mr. Cass is a senior fellow at the Manhattan Institute. This article was adapted from his essay, “More Perfect Unions,” in City Journal’s “The Shape of Work to Come” issue.

Advertisements

Leave a Reply

Fill in your details below or click an icon to log in:

WordPress.com Logo

You are commenting using your WordPress.com account. Log Out / Change )

Twitter picture

You are commenting using your Twitter account. Log Out / Change )

Facebook photo

You are commenting using your Facebook account. Log Out / Change )

Google+ photo

You are commenting using your Google+ account. Log Out / Change )

Connecting to %s